#246: The Surplus Energy Economy, part 1

FROM FIRST PRINCIPLES

Introduction

We have reached a turning-point at which economics and the economy have parted company. Orthodox economics continues to promise growth in perpetuity, but the economy itself is going in the opposite direction.

The explanation for this is simple. Conventional economics assumes that the economy is driven by money, which is entirely under our control. But the economy is, in reality, not a financial system, but a physical one, which uses energy to convert raw materials into the products and services which constitute prosperity. The modern economy has been built on abundant, low-cost energy from fossil fuels, but this dynamic is winding down and, as we shall see in a future instalment, we have no complete (or timely) alternative with which to replace it.

The aim with The Surplus Energy Economy is to set out a comprehensive assessment of the condition and prospects of the world economy and financial system, seen from the perspective that the economy is shaped by energy, not money. This series of articles will be as specific as possible, using data from the SEEDS economic model.

The conclusions reached here necessarily contradict the orthodox line, which is that the supposed ‘normality’ of growth will soon return, and that seamless transition to renewable energy sources will deliver economic expansion in perpetuity.

The economy is analysed here as a material system which has started to contract after reaching physical constraints imposed by the availability and cost of energy. Similar limits apply to environmental tolerance for energy-based economic activity.

Findings will come later in this series, but we are completely unprepared for the reversal of prior growth in the economy. The ending of growth has not arrived without warning, and we can identify a precursor zone, starting in the 1990s, which was characterised by deceleration, followed by stagnation.

Rendered myopic by denial, and misled by a mistaken economic orthodoxy, we have been attempting the impossible task of fixing material economic problems with monetary tools. As we shall see, this has placed global finance at systemic risk.

An economy on the turn

The consensus view of current global economic problems is that they are temporary, and largely traceable to pandemic lockdowns and the war in Eastern Europe, though some observers do concede that excessive use of QE might have been a factor in the recent resurgence of inflation.

These, though, are explanations rooted in orthodox economics, which makes many fallacious assumptions. One is that the economy is entirely a financial system, not constrained by energy, resource or environmental limitations. Another is that the economy can grow in perpetuity, notwithstanding the limited physical characteristics of the Earth.

The concept of ‘infinite growth on a finite planet’ isn’t a logical proposition, but it’s been a mightily persuasive one.

Evidence is accumulating in support of an alternative view, which is that the economy is a material system, subject to physical constraints, and that economic prosperity is determined by energy, not money. Surplus Energy Economics interprets the economy in this way, and models it on this basis using SEEDS (the Surplus Energy Economics Data System).

Energy interpretation of the economy isn’t going to be accepted by the mainstream any time soon, and not just because it demonstrates the fallacies of orthodox economics. Energy-based analysis tells us that economic growth, far from continuing indefinitely, has already decelerated via stagnation into contraction.

This has never been a remotely acceptable conclusion where the ‘powers that be’ – or, for that matter, the general public – are concerned. Over a very long period, we have been using monetary gimmickry in futile efforts to reinvigorate a floundering economy. But trying to fix a material economic problem with financial tools can be compared to trying to cure an ailing house-plant with a spanner.

These efforts have led, via the global financial crisis (GFC) of 2008-09 and a subsequent era of monetary recklessness, to a point of systemic risk in global finance. We have a ludicrously-inflated “everything bubble” in asset prices and, even more seriously, an enormous complex of inter-connected liabilities which the system cannot possibly honour ‘for value’.

Why, though, are economics and the economy going in different directions?

Origins – ‘the class of ‘76’

When the year 1776 is mentioned, it probably reminds people chiefly of the Declaration of Independence, from which date the history of the United States begins. But two other events of profound importance also happened in that year, and both of them took place in Scotland. James Watt completed the first truly efficient steam engine in 1776, whilst Adam Smith published An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations in the same year.

The importance of these breakthroughs is scarcely capable of exaggeration. Watt gave the world the ability to convert heat into work, which enabled us to harness the vast energy resources contained in coal, oil and natural gas. Smith’s book, generally referred to as The Wealth of Nations, was the founding treatise of classical economics.

A significant distinction needs to be noted from the outset. James Watt was an engineer and inventor, and his practical work laid the foundations for a vast expansion in the material economy of products and services. Adam Smith was primarily a philosopher – he considered The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759) his finest work – and can be described as a theoretician, setting out his explanation of the economy in terms of the working of money.

It’s worth remembering, too, that Smith was describing an agrarian economy, and could not have anticipated the coming of the Industrial Revolution. No-one should doubt the importance of Smith’s ground-breaking work, but we are entitled to wonder why, more than two centuries into the Industrial Age, his successors continue to adhere to the precepts of an economy shaped by money alone, not subject to material constraints, and capable of defying logic by delivering “infinite growth on a finite planet”.

The activities which began with ‘the class of ‘76’ have continued in parallel ever since. The heirs to Watt created the huge and complex economy of modern times, accomplished on the basis of energy from fossil fuels. Classical economists, who are the heirs to Smith, have purported to explain this dramatic expansion in terms, not of material energy, but of money, which is an immaterial human artefact used primarily for the exchange – not the creation – of the products and services made available by the harnessing of energy.

So long as the economy continued to expand, there was no necessary conflict, other than at the intellectual level, between these two schools of thought. The beneficiaries of economic growth could thank Watt for their improving prosperity, or hand the credit to Smith, with most people probably giving scant thought to either.

Now, though, we have reached a parting of the ways between economics and the economy. It’s becoming increasingly apparent that economic growth, having decelerated since at least the 1990s (and arguably for a lot longer than that), has gone into reverse.

Classical economics says that this can’t happen. As we shall see, observation makes it increasingly clear that it has.

This presents us with a choice of two interpretations. One, favoured here, is that prior growth in prosperity has reversed because the fossil fuel dynamic has been winding down. The other is that we can restore the economy to perpetual expansion if we work along the monetary lines specified by classical economics.

The existence of ample intellectual and observational evidence makes it imperative that we take note of economic deterioration, and then seek explanations for why it has been happening. In the modern parlance, there is a range of “narratives” which purport to tell us why the economy is struggling. We looked at these rival explanations in a previous article, so need not distract ourselves by revisiting them now.

The line of inquiry followed here is based on reasoning from first principles within a framework of evidence. Our conclusions are simply stated.

Prior growth in the industrial economy has gone into reverse, because the dynamic built on fossil fuel energy has decelerated, over a lengthy period of time, to a point of trend reversal which we might, if we so choose, call “inflexion”. There exists no plausible alternative that offers a complete and timely replacement for the economic value hitherto sourced from oil, gas and coal.

This means that, in material terms, the world is getting poorer. We can see this happening, if we choose to look. At the same time, energy-intensive necessities are becoming more expensive. The ensuing contraction in discretionary prosperity is one of the main economic problems created by this process.

The other is the unravelling of the vast financial system predicated entirely on the assumption that the underlying economy of products and services could never cease to grow, let alone start to contract.

Foundation principles

The Surplus Energy Economics interpretation of the economy reasons from first principles, of which there are three.

First, the economy is an energy system, because literally nothing that has any economic value at all can be supplied without the use of energy. Other raw materials, including food and water as well as minerals and plastics, are functions of the energy required to make them available. Energy is ‘the master resource’, and is the obvious connection between our economic and environmental challenges.

To be slightly more specific, the modern economy is a dissipative landfill system. Energy is used to convert raw materials into products whose ultimate destination is disposal. This is dissipative because, in thermodynamic terms, this process involves the conversion of concentrated, dense energy into the diffuse format of waste heat. The use of fossil fuels as the concentrated input to this process means that the resulting waste heat contains climate-harming gases.

The second principle is that energy is never ‘free’. Whenever energy is accessed for our use, some of that energy is always consumed in the access process. Energy is used at every stage in the creation, maintenance, operation and replacement of the systems which supply us with energy. This ‘consumed in access’ component is a cost deduction, because it is energy which cannot be used for any other economic purpose. It can be thought of as a rent levied upon economic activity by the material character of energy resources.

It is known here as the Energy Cost of Energy, giving us the principle of ECoE.

This means that material prosperity is a product of the supply, value and cost of energy. Prosperity, therefore, is, first and foremost, a material concept, not a financial one.

Money has no intrinsic worth, but commands value only as a man-made ‘claim’ on the material output of the energy economy. It is worthless unless there is something material for which it can be exchanged.

Our third and final principle is that of money as claim.

‘Two economies’

As well as being self-evident, these principles lead us to an obvious conclusion. This is that we need to think conceptually in terms of ‘two economies’. One of these is the ‘real’ or material economy of products and services made available by the use of energy. The other is the ‘financial’ or parallel economy of money and credit.

From this, it follows that the financial economy is a representational counterpart or proxy of the real economy. If these ‘two economies’ are in a reasonably close relationship, we are in a situation of equilibrium where the claims that constitute the financial system can be honoured by the material economy.

As we shall see, the situation now is one of extreme disequilibrium, meaning that we have created an enormous quantity of excess claims which cannot be ‘honoured for value’. This is why major downsizing of the financial system has become inescapable, and will look like ‘value destruction’.

The reality – though it’s of scant comfort – is that much of the ‘value’ that will be destroyed never really existed in the first place, and consisted of monetary claims that the real economy of the future was never going to be able to honour. We are, in fact, in two bubbles – the “everything bubble” in asset prices, which is destined to burst, and the ‘delusion bubble’ of gigantic financial commitments that must be relinquished because they cannot possibly be honoured.

A brief history of now

The central proposition which emerges from first principles is that prosperity is a function of surplus energy, meaning total energy less the ECoE cost of making that energy available for use.

In pre-industrial times, almost all energy was sourced from human and animal labour. The dynamic here was that human energy was obtained from nutrition, and expended in hunting or finding that nutritional energy. The same equation exists in nature, where an animal or a bird survives only if the energy sourced from consuming food exceeds the energy expended in obtaining it.

Agriculture made this process more efficient without, of course, changing the fundamental dynamic. If, say, twenty people could now be fed by the labour of nineteen, an energy surplus existed which enabled the release of the twentieth person for non-subsistence activities. These activities were varied, and included capital investment in buildings, tools and infrastructure, all of which increase productivity in the future by sacrificing consumption in the present. But a surplus of 1/20 is very small, which explains why pre-industrial systems of investment, craft manufacture, education, law and government were rudimentary by later standards.

Accessing fossil fuels was completely transformative. In today’s developed economies, very few people work in agriculture, and their labour is supplemented enormously by inputs and services made available by fossil fuel energy. Modern agriculture, no less than industry, is a system built on oil, gas and coal.

Classical economics, which traces its origins to the pre-industrial era, is prone to ignoring the energy dynamic to the point of absurdity. For example, the statistic that only about 6% of world GDP is attributable to agriculture leads to the absurd proposition that the remaining 94% of the economy could carry on unaffected if we lost the ability to produce food. In many economies, activities like tourism and financial services are statistically larger proportions of GDP than agriculture or the supply of energy, and are thus deemed to be ‘more important’, and worthier of more investment and policy attention, than these basics.

Classical economics side-steps issues of scarcity by promising infinite substitutability, a claim which, where energy is concerned, is now being disproved, with brutal economic consequences.

Conventional economics has been described as “the dismal science” and, whilst it might indeed be dismal, it certainly isn’t a science. What classical economics is pleased to call the “laws” of economics are merely observations about the behaviour of the human artefact of money, and are in no way analogous to the laws of science.

It hardly needs be said that energy cannot be lent into existence by commercial banks, or created out of the ether by central bankers. We can’t overcome environmental problems by sending a cheque to the universe, and neither, for that matter, can we make energy transition to renewables possible by using QE – any such exercise would be self-defeating, because it would simply push up the prices of every raw material input required for the expansion and maintenance of renewables.

Output and prosperity

Two terms used frequently here are output and prosperity, and we need to be clear about the difference between them. The understanding of prosperity, defined in material terms, ought to be the primary objective of economics, and the calculation of prosperity is at the centre of the SEEDS economic model.

The difference between output and prosperity is cost, much as necessary expenses are the difference between individuals’ total and disposable incomes. At the macroeconomic level, output is the value created by the use of energy, and prosperity is what remains after ECoE has been deducted from output thus defined.

The principal metric in orthodox macroeconomics is gross domestic product, which is often, – though quite mistakenly – assumed to be a measure of output or prosperity. In fact, GDP is a quantification of financial transactional activity, and it’s perfectly possible, indeed commonplace, for transactions to take place without any economic value being created.

One technical point needs to be made here before we examine economic output. There are two ways in which other currencies can be converted into dollars for purposes of comparison and global aggregation. One of these is to use market exchange rates, and the other is known as purchasing power parity (PPP). PPP is the convention used in measuring global growth, and it is the one used here, except where otherwise stated. Monetary amounts need to be expressed at constant (‘real’) values, so the nomenclature is ‘$PPP 2021’. SEEDS analysis of national economies is undertaken in local currencies, again at constant 2021 values.

When it comes to internationally-comparable conventional economic statistics, the International Monetary Fund can be regarded as authoritative. In its most recent set of data, published in October, the IMF stated that world gross domestic product fell by 3.0% in 2020, during pandemic lockdowns, grew by 6.0% in 2021, and was likely to have increased by 3.2% during 2022.

From the same source, world GDP was $146 trillion (PPP) in 2021. Adjusted for broad inflation (using the GDP deflator), the equivalent number for 2001 was $73tn, meaning that reported real GDP doubled (+101%) between those years.

Over the same period, though, global debt increased by 180% in real terms, in a relationship illustrated in Fig. 1. Over a period in which reported GDP grew by $73tn, total public and private debt expanded by $232tn (Fig. 1A), meaning that each dollar of reported growth was accompanied by $3.15 of net new borrowing. Another way to look at this is that borrowing averaged 10.8% of GDP during a period in which reported growth in GDP averaged 3.4% (Fig. 1B).

For the United States, growth in GDP of USD 7.3tn (46%) was accompanied by a USD 34tn (115%) increase in aggregate debt. On this basis, USD 4.66 of net new debt was added for each dollar of reported growth, whilst borrowing averaged 8.9% of GDP during a period when GDP itself grew at an annual average rate of 1.9%.

Fig. 1

Given that GDP is a measure of transactions, a direct connection exists between borrowing and changes in GDP. A simple example illustrates this point. If a government were to use borrowed money to employ 10,000 people to dig holes in roads, and another 10,000 to fill them in again, the wages paid to both groups would be added to GDP, even though no economic value has been added. The spending of these wages would contribute to GDP measured as expenditures and, most absurdly, the work would count as ‘value added’ for computational purposes, even though no such value has in fact been created.

The cost of employing these workers would be added to government debt, where it would be disregarded by anyone choosing not to make the connection between the two. The technical terms for these are flow (in this instance, of GDP) and stock (of debt).

What this amounts to is that you can report just about as much “growth” as you like, depending upon how much you are willing and able to borrow. Historic data illustrates this connection. Between 2001 and 2021, average growth in the United States was 1.9%, and annual borrowing averaged 8.9% of GDP, as we have seen. China reported far more growth than America over this period (averaging 7.8%), but also borrowed very much more (an average of 24.7% of GDP).

A reflection on absurdities

This relationship between stock and flow cautions us, not just against an unquestioning acceptance of GDP as a measure of output, but also against relying on the ratio of debt to GDP, because these are not discrete data series.

We are sometimes told that debt “doesn’t matter”, which, of course, is absurd. We are also informed that borrowing now can create growth which, in due course, ‘pays off’ the debt taken on to create it. Individual enterprises can indeed do this, but a borrowing-to-growth ratio of 3:1 (and often higher) makes this a mathematical absurdity at the macroeconomic level.

Whilst we’re pondering absurdities, few are more readily accepted than aggregate ‘valuations’ of assets. We are routinely told that market movements have ‘added’ or ‘wiped out’ billions, or even trillions, in investor value. Statisticians – who really should know better – frequently tot up the supposed value of property and other assets and then deduct liabilities to produce a ‘national balance sheet’. The results usually echo Harold MacMillan when he told the British public (in 1957) that they’d “never had it so good”.

The reality, of course, is that the only potential buyers for the entirety of a nation’s housing stock are the same people to whom it already belongs. Foreign buyers don’t affect this other than at the margin and, in any case, their investment merely shifts property demand between countries.

The same applies to any asset class, including stocks and bonds. Aggregates are arrived at by multiplying average prices by the number of units of the asset in question. This implies that the entire asset class could be sold for that sum, which is completely impossible. The error involved here is the application of marginal transaction prices to the aggregate of stock.

Property is an appropriate example, because we are often treated to the proposition that real property prices can never fall because ‘demand is always increasing as population numbers expand’. The mistake made in such glib statements is the conflation of ‘demand’ with ‘want’. You or I might ‘want’ a new sports car, but that ‘want’ only counts as demand to the extent that we have the wherewithal to implement it. Likewise, ‘wanting’ or ‘needing’ a home does not count as ‘demand’ unless prices are within the reach of those who want or need one.

It’s much more meaningful to think of asset prices as the inverse of the cost of capital. What this in turn means is that stock – not just of asset values, but of liability viability as well – is a temporal function of economic flow.

This leads us, as a precursor to measuring prosperity, into a consideration of what really constitutes economic ‘output’.

Underlying output

As we have seen, much of the economic ‘growth’ of recent times has been created by credit expansion. The SEEDS economic model strips out this ‘credit effect’ to calculate underlying or ‘clean’ economic output, known here as C-GDP.

This is illustrated in Fig. 2. On this adjusted basis, underlying annual average growth in the global economy between 2001 and 2021 was only 1.6%, rather than the reported 3.4% (Fig. 2A).

Over this period, the expansion in C-GDP was only $27tn, or 39%, rather than the reported increase of $73tn, or 101% (Fig. 2B). Put another way, within total reported growth in the global economy over those two decades, only 37% ranks as organic expansion, and the remaining 63% was the cosmetic effect of pouring huge amounts of borrowed money into the system, and counting the ensuing transactions as ‘output’.

Fig. 2

We can ‘cut to the chase’ here by looking back at Fig. 1A and asking ourselves whether the pattern illustrated there is sustainable – in other words, can we carry on, indefinitely, adding more than $3 of debt for each $1 of “growth”, or does a point arrive at which it becomes apparent that this debt can never be repaid?

When that point does arrive – which, of course, it must, and perhaps now has – the result is a collapse in confidence, which happens at the moment when enough people realize that debts and other commitments owed to them cannot be honoured ‘for value’. This will trigger defaults, which may be ‘hard’ (reneging on debts), ‘soft’ (allowing inflation to destroy the real value of debt repayment), or a combination of the two. Since one person’s debt is another person’s asset, there is no cost-free way of simply writing off outstanding debts.

One thing is certain – we cannot create material economic value by borrowing, or by producing new money out of the ether.

The energy connection

For most purposes, the SEEDS calculation of C-GDP commences in 2000 – as we scroll back through the 1990s and beyond, necessary data for some economies is not available, and starting more than two decades ago provides a sufficiency of historic information for our purposes.

In a recent exercise, though, the SEEDS clock on global C-GDP was started, not in 2000, but in 1980, and the results of this investigation, when compared with energy use, were startling. As illustrated in Fig. 3, the relationship between underlying economic output (C-GDP) and primary energy consumption was not just linear but strikingly consistent (Fig. 3A).

The ratio of economic output and energy use, shown in Fig. 3B, didn’t vary by more than +/- 4% in any one of the forty-two years between 1980 and 2021. Given the vicissitudes experienced in both the economy and the supply of energy over that very lengthy period, this consistency is remarkable (and was completely unexpected before the calculations were made).

Fig. 3

This finding might seem surprising, because it implies that there has been no improvement, over a very long period, in the efficiency with which energy is converted into economic value.

There are a number of possible explanations, and these might repay investigation in the future. Just one of these may be that advances in efficiency are cancelled out by deterioration in the quality of non-energy raw materials. In minerals, for example, a decline in ore densities could easily offset any progress made in the efficiency of extraction and processing.

Be that as it may, the clear implication is that we cannot “de-couple” the generation of economic value from the quantitative use of energy. As you may know, the European Environmental Bureau dismissed the concept of de-coupling in a 2019 paper entitled Decoupling debunked: Why green growth is not enough. The report remarked that the case that has been made for de-coupling is “a haystack without a needle”.

Energy itself will be addressed later in this series, but the general conclusion is that the availability of primary energy is poised to decrease, mainly because the supply of alternatives, such as renewables, nuclear and hydroelectricity, will not be able to expand at rates sufficient to offset the impending decline in the production of fossil fuels.

From an environmental perspective, this is positive, but we should be in no doubt at all that a decreasing availability of primary energy means that economic output will contract. The economic outlook suggests broad re-prioritization, and this might provide a modest, and probably transitory, improvement in conversion efficiency (see Fig. 3C). But we should be in no doubt that reduced energy use will result in a smaller economy (Fig. 3D).

Starting from first principles, we have seen how economic output is a linear function of the energy available to the system. In the next article, we’ll look at how the cost of energy feeds into these equations, and how we can conclude – whisper it who dares – that prior growth in material prosperity has gone into reverse.

#245: 2023 – Navigating the narratives

FACING FACTS, RELYING ON REASON

At the start of 2023, an impartial observer could easily conclude that ‘the world has gone mad’. This is most evident in what is sometimes called ‘the public discourse’. Where our economic prospects are concerned, what we are witnessing must rank as the most extreme case of collective denial ever experienced.

Few would dispute that the economy went badly awry last year. In concrete terms, there were widespread and severe falls in living standards, whilst the cost of mortgages and credit rose markedly. Asset prices started their descent from absurdly over-inflated levels.

But there’s a lot that didn’t happen in 2022, but may be lying in wait in the year ahead. Air has started to leak out of the “everything bubble” but it hasn’t, thus far, actually burst, as most bubbles do. We’ve yet to see a cascade of defaults on credit commitments, though this could be a logical corollary of asset price slumps (which impair collateral), and of declining household disposable incomes and falling corporate profitability, most obviously in discretionary sectors.

This is for real

This isn’t intended as a forecast, and we cannot rule out a gradual retreat from the excesses fuelled by a combination of economic deterioration, cheap credit and cheaper money.

Rather, the point is that we need to take this very seriously indeed, and that’s the intention here. The world is awash with “narratives”, and this combines with two factors – the rapidity of change, and the highly elevated levels of risk – to require a focus on what we can know, rather than on what we can only speculate about.

Where “narratives” are concerned, the orthodox line remains that, once the pandemic and the war in Eastern Europe are behind us, the global economy will return to perpetual growth, with technology delivering a shiny new world of prosperity powered by limitless amounts of climate-friendly renewable energy.

This, both in detail and in toto, is at the far end of implausible. Growth in material prosperity has gone into reverse, and claims to the contrary are in direct conflict, not just with logical analysis, but with the lived experiences of millions as well.

De-globalization is already underway, and the much more serious process of the de-financialization of the economy comes next.

This situation presents us with choices. We can participate in collective denial, or we can analyse the economic and broader situation from a rational point of view, founded in first principles. The latter approach is preferred here. Effective analysis of the economy is perfectly possible, but its results are unpalatable to what we might term ‘the generality of opinion’.

The facts of the matter are simply stated. The harnessing of abundant, low-cost energy from coal, oil and natural gas triggered two centuries of remarkable economic growth. Now, though, fossil fuel energy has ceased to be low-cost and can be expected, in consequence, to become a lot less abundant as well. With no complete replacement available for the energy value hitherto sourced from fossil fuels, the economy can only contract.

In no particular order of priority, our second problem is the environmental and ecological harm inflicted by historic and continuing use of carbon energy. On the basis of fossil fuels, the economy has evolved into a dissipative landfill system. Energy is used to process raw materials into products whose ultimate (and usually rapid) destination is disposal. This involves the conversion of energy from concentrated into diffuse form. The latter is waste heat which, in a system powered by fossil fuels, contains climate-harming gases.

None of what we are experiencing now has happened without prior warning. The remarkably prescient The Limits to Growth (LtG), published back in 1972, used system dynamics to forecast declines in industrial output and the supply of raw materials, combined with a worsening in what was then termed “pollution”. These warnings were very largely ignored, not because they were wrong, but because they were inconvenient.

At a humbler and less ambitious level, the SEEDS economic model provides a nearer-term, financially-calibrated interpretation which accords with the prognosis of LtG.

SEEDS draws two important distinctions. One of these is the difference between economic output and material prosperity. The other is the distinction between the ‘real’ or material economy of energy and the ‘financial’ or proxy economy of money and credit.

The interpretation and projections produced by SEEDS are unsettling, in that they involve a continuing deterioration in material prosperity and the fracturing of a financial system entirely predicated on the assumption that prior growth in the economy could never go into reverse.

A series of outcomes follows from this. The first is that, whilst prosperity erodes, the real costs of energy-intensive necessities will rise. This process of affordability compression has two principal effects. One is that consumption of discretionary products and services will contract, and the other is that payment streams from households to the corporate and financial sectors will be undermined.

The latter takes us into the financial system, where successive exercises in denial-gimmickry have created an enormous bubble in asset prices, and a gigantic network of interconnected financial commitments that cannot be honoured. Where these liabilities are concerned, we don’t even have complete data, let alone plans for managing a contraction which seems likely to be disorderly. One consequence is that, whilst the onset of ‘de-globalization’ has started to gain some notice, the process of de-financialization has not.

As assumptions degrade, narratives proliferate

During two centuries of rapid economic expansion, various observations have taken on the status of certainties. Quite naturally, people have come to believe that economic expansion is the natural order of things. Few may pay much attention to announcements about rising GDP – the metric which purports to measure prosperity – but it has long been taken for granted that the material circumstances of individuals and families will improve over time, and that children will be better off than their parents were at any given age.

What we have been experiencing in recent years has been the rapid degradation of such certainties. How individuals react to this dislocation necessarily varies. Some take a “Pollyanna” stance, embracing denial, and accepting the line that growth will resume once the sheer bad luck of a pandemic and a war in quick succession is behind us.

Others, translating “Bond villains” from book and screen to real life, seek someone to blame, which could be anyone from Mr Putin to schemers plotting in the shadows. Still others side with Cassandra, predicting imminent collapse and dusting off the old sandwich-boards of “The End is Nigh!”

It seems likely that there’s a large and growing fourth strand of opinion which, whilst uncommitted to any of the above, is mystified and increasingly suspicious. For many, bafflement and mistrust may be just a few short steps from anger.

The approach preferred here is that of rational analysis and informed debate. I believe that the best process for the advancement of understanding is courteous, informed and reasoned discussion, and I am deeply grateful to everyone who has contributed to our conversations over the past twelve months. A notable milestone was passed in 2022 when, for the first time, more than 80,000 different people from around the world – to be exact, from 154 countries – visited this site at least once.

The immediate plan is to set out a comprehensive statement of what we know about the economy and the financial system from the energy-based perspective. This cannot be accomplished in a single article, but it seems important that we codify our understanding.

Finally, it’s worth remarking that the dissipative-landfill model isn’t some kind of eternal verity. It isn’t the only way to manage the provision of goods and services to the public, and it didn’t exist in anything like its current form before the Industrial Revolution.

The pre-industrial economy might be described as sustainable, but there are two big snags with trying to create “sustainable 2.0”. The first of these is that the global population now numbers eight billion, up from about 660 million in 1776, when the first efficient mechanism for converting heat into work was unveiled.

The second is that the immaterial end-product of the dissipative-landfill system is a set of entrenched attitudes, assumptions which are now colliding with the reality of resource and environmental limits.

Life in agrarian times wasn’t a bucolic idyll and, in any case, we can’t go back to it. What we can do is to analyse the unfolding situation objectively, looking for rationally-based visibility on how events are likely to unfold.

Whilst anyone can leap to conclusions and assumptions, knowledge can only be reached through plodding and faltering steps.